• IP addresses are NOT logged in this forum so there's no point asking. Please note that this forum is full of homophobes, racists, lunatics, schizophrenics & absolute nut jobs with a smattering of geniuses, Chinese chauvinists, Moderate Muslims and last but not least a couple of "know-it-alls" constantly sprouting their dubious wisdom. If you believe that content generated by unsavory characters might cause you offense PLEASE LEAVE NOW! Sammyboy Admin and Staff are not responsible for your hurt feelings should you choose to read any of the content here.

    The OTHER forum is HERE so please stop asking.

Survey: PAPee Ministees Are OVERPAID!

makapaaa

Alfrescian (Inf)
Asset
<TABLE cellSpacing=0 cellPadding=0 width="100%" border=0><TBODY><TR>Yes, bankers were overpaid; no, it won't last
</TR><!-- headline one : end --><!-- Author --><TR><TD class="padlrt8 georgia11 darkgrey bold" colSpan=2>By Floyd Norris
</TD></TR><!-- show image if available --></TBODY></TABLE>




<!-- START OF : div id="storytext"--><!-- more than 4 paragraphs -->It is one thing when the best-paid people seem to be the smartest and the most accomplished. Those who make much less may not like it, but the differential seems understandable.
It is another thing when those people are shown to have committed huge blunders that would have driven their companies out of business, and them into the unemployment line, but for government bailouts.
So it is now with Wall Street. In both Europe and the United States, antipathy towards the bailout is rising amid complaints that the money has not helped the economy by encouraging loans, but has kept the bankers in champagne and caviar.
Are financial workers overpaid? And if so, will it continue? The answers, according to a new study by two economists, are yes, they are overpaid, and no, it will not last.

=> Now u wanna understand why the Papayas insist on pegging their pay to the highest paid?

'Wages in finance were excessively high around 1930 and from the mid-1990s until 2006,' wrote Assistant Professor Thomas Philippon of New York University (NYU) and Professor Ariell Reshef of the University of Virginia, in a National Bureau of Economic Research working paper released last week - Wages and Human Capital in the US Financial Industry, 1909-2006.
They forecast that up to half of the wage differential observed in recent years 'can be expected to disappear'. They won't disappear overnight, of course.
The sad story of how Merrill Lynch bosses handed out bonuses just before the Bank of America takeover was completed - and just before about US$15 billion (S$22.5 billion) in losses materialised from Merrill's portfolio - reinforces the suspicion that Wall Streeters see themselves as entitled to outsize pay cheques even if their companies are failing.
But even in the Depression the adjustment took time. The professors calculated that relative financial wages, taking into account education and other demographic factors, declined sharply in the 1930s and then at a slower pace until about 1980, when there was virtually no difference.
Then, in a new era of financial innovation, 'the financial sector became once again a high-skill, high-wage industry', Prof Philippon wrote on the NYU website last week.
It may be no accident that New York City, the country's financial capital, went broke in the 1970s as financial industry wages approached their low point. Nor is it surprising that Manhattan real estate prices soared in the 1990s and early in this decade as multi-million-dollar Wall Street bonuses pushed up demand for high-end apartments.
If relative wages are set to decline, the pain in New York could be greater than in other regions.
The authors offered several reasons why financial salaries soared in the 1920s and again since 1980.
It isn't computers, they argued, because there were no computers the first time, and it is not just a strong stock market. Instead, they attributed it in part to strong demand for financial analysis at a time when technical revolutions were leading to an explosion of new stock offerings and loans to young and risky companies.

=> In other words, scientists and engineers do the work while the cunning and ruthless enjoy the fruit. Just like what the Familee and its dogs have been doing?

Before 1930, that was the electrical revolution.
More recently, it was information technology.
There is also the lure of increasing financial innovation, which they said is least likely to occur when there is more regulation.
'Highly skilled labour left the financial sector in the wake of Depression-era regulations, and started flowing back precisely when these regulations were removed.'
The authors noted that risky debt was popular in the 1920s, then all but disappeared until the 1970s brought junk bonds. Such debt, they noted, is used to finance companies with high growth potential, but skilled analysis is required.
'This explains the dynamics of rating agencies, which were important players in the inter-war period, small and largely irrelevant in the 1950s and 1960s, and growing fast from the 1970s until today,' they wrote.
By the peak of the credit boom, rating agencies were essential to financial innovation; they had deve-
loped models that somehow proved that there was little risk for investors who put up most of the money for very risky loans. The models turned out to be very wrong.
As a result of the current crisis, much of that innovation now seems foolish or even criminal.
Without the innovation, banks could never have issued sub-prime mortgages with teaser interest rates that would later soar. Nor could such mortgages have been bundled into securitisations financed largely by AAA-rated investments.
Nor could regulators have been persuaded that the banks' own risk models should be used to evaluate the safety of the banks.
'In retrospect,' the authors wrote, 'it is clear that regulators did not have the human capital to keep up with the financial industry, and to understand it well enough to be able to exert effective regulation.
'Given the wage premia that we document, it was impossible for regulators to attract and retain highly skilled financial workers.'
'Of course,' they added, 'regulators will be able to hire cheap skilled labour this year, just as they were able to in the 1930s.'
Just how much the demand for financial innovation will fade is unclear, of course. 'These things come in waves,' Prof Philippon said in an interview. 'If for the next 10 years, we go back to a 60s-style economy, where big firms make investments without taking too much risk, finance will shrink.'
But, he added, if the green revolution, alternative energy and biotech 'turn out to be like electricity, then we will need them'.
He is convinced that less financial innovation could be good for a time, and that this crisis has shown to all that much more regulation is needed.
'Some of the financial innovations we have seen are obviously inefficient,' he said. 'A good chunk of innovation has to do with tax and regulation arbitrage. That is really a waste for the society.'
And, he added, the society could benefit from a flow to other industries.
'As a society, do we want to put a third of our best brains in the financial sector?' he asked, pointing to a study indicating Harvard graduates from the early 1990s were far more likely to go into finance than were those who had graduated a decade earlier.
New York Times
<HR width="50%" SIZE=1>

The authors offered several reasons why financial salaries soared in the 1920s and again since 1980. It isn't computers, they argued, because there were no computers the first time, and it is not just a strong stock market. Instead, they attributed it in part to strong demand for financial analysis at a time when technical revolutions were leading to an explosion of new stock offerings and loans to young and risky companies.
 
Top